...
...
Boundaries of Competition in Labor Markets: An Analysis in Terms of No-Poaching Agreements and Ancillary Restraints Defense

...

Boundaries of Competition in Labor Markets: An Analysis in Terms of No-Poaching Agreements and Ancillary Restraints Defense

Posted | Updated by Insights team:

Publication | Update:

Mar 2024
...

The consecutive investigations initiated by the Competition Board ("Board") due to competition...

The consecutive investigations initiated by the Competition Board ("Board") due to competition violations in labor markets, with the first one in 2021, have stirred significant attention. Following the investigations concerning 32 undertakings, primarily consisting of innovation-based technology companies, which resulted in substantial administrative fines imposed on some of the undertakings within the scope of the investigation, the investigations initiated against 19 undertakings operating mainly in the pharmaceutical sector and the recently concluded investigation targeting enterprises operating in the information technology sector indicate that the Board will continue to maintain the hot topic of competition issues in labor markets and support the anticipation that numerous inspections will be conducted to ensure competition in labor markets by scrutinizing different sectors.

What are No-Poaching Agreements?

No-poaching agreements are agreements, either directly or indirectly established, where an undertaking refrains from offering jobs to, or hiring, the employees of another undertaking. These agreements are commonly made between employers, although they can also occur between employers and labor providers. Such agreements, where businesses mutually refrain from competing for limited labor resources, can be deemed as a violation of competition law since they have the potential to restrict competition in the labor market.

These types of agreements can take different forms between employers or between employers and labor providers. Among two or more employers, an agreement can be reached regarding not poaching or hiring certain employees, or employers can reach an agreement with labor providers (such as recruitment firms) not to hire or poach specific employees. It is possible to say that such agreements can be strictly enforced or implemented in a more flexible manner with mutual consent. For example, the agreement may include provisions for the parties not to poach each other's employees and not to make any exceptions to this rule. In another scenario, undertakings can limit employee transfers flexibly based on a mutual approval mechanism. In this case, the parties do not completely prohibit employee transfers, but only allow transfers that they mutually approve.

No-poaching agreements can negatively impact competition in the labor market and restrict employees' freedom to find new jobs or switch jobs. Consequently, competition authorities in many countries deem these agreements as contrary to competition laws and prohibit them. The primary criterion in assessing these agreements is whether there is an agreement on anti-competitive behavior regarding labor resources.

No-poaching agreements are not always considered a competition violation.
For example, an undertaking providing information technology services to its customers may wish to include provisions in the contracts with their customers to prevent the hiring of key personnel who play crucial roles in the services provided to the customers, either while the contractual relationship between the parties is ongoing or for a certain period after its termination, to be employed within the customers' organizations. In this case, the service provider may reasonably request the inclusion of such a provision in the contract to protect the time, effort, and expenses invested in training and supporting their personnel. Similarly, customers may also try to prevent service providers from hiring their own personnel. This is often because customers typically have smaller teams compared to the service provider's relevant business unit and have invested significant time and effort in training their personnel. Additionally, customers may be concerned about increasing their dependence on service providers if key employees are transferred by them. Therefore, customers may also request agreements regarding no-poaching to be made verbally or in writing in contracts they enter into with service providers.

No-Poaching Agreements in the Context of Ancillary Restraints Doctrine

Ancillary restraints are defined as restrictions that are imposed on the parties of an agreement which, although not constituting the essence of the agreement, are necessary for achieving the objectives intended by the agreement and are directly related to those objectives. In the Guidelines on Relevant Undertakings, Turnover, and Ancillary Restraints in Mergers and Acquisitions, the concept of ancillary restraint is described as restrictions directly related to and necessary for the implementation of the concentration process and for fully realizing the expected efficiencies from the concentration.

A no-poaching agreement, if not directly related to or necessary for a legitimate cooperation between employers (such as a merger or joint venture), is considered a naked restraint.

In practice, there are many examples where no-poaching agreements are considered ancillary restraints in the context of mergers and joint ventures. Indeed, mergers and joint ventures demonstrate legitimate cooperation between the parties, and provisions regarding no-poaching under the ancillary restraint doctrine are objectively analyzed in terms of the criteria of "direct relevance" and "necessity".

In U.S. antitrust law, the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission evaluate naked no-poaching agreements and wage-fixing agreements as anticompetitive and categorize them as per se violations of competition law.

In European Union competition law, no-poaching provisions in concentration transactions are considered "ancillary restraints" as long as they meet the criteria of direct relevance and necessity and are not directly prohibited. However, agreements between competing undertakings on issues such as determining employment conditions, setting terms related to fringe benefits, and fixing wages are also considered restrictive of competition by the European Commission and EU competition authorities.

In recent years, developments in the evaluation of no-poaching agreements have sparked discussions on whether such agreements could be considered as ancillary restraints in agreements between competitors or in other vertical relationships such as supplier-buyer relationships, outside of concentration operations. Particularly in their defense, undertakings have argued that the provisions related to no-poaching under review should be considered as ancillary restraints, and therefore cannot be deemed as an absolute violation in terms of restricting competition. The discussions surrounding investigations and inquiries into sectors scrutinized for labor market issues have become quite significant in our country lately. The approach of the Board, which emphasizes the necessity for a restriction to be explicitly agreed upon in writing and for its boundaries to be clearly defined for it to be considered as an ancillary restraint, has added a new dimension to this debate. However, due to the absence of a legal rule mandating that ancillary restraints must be in writing, the Board's requirement of this condition has been subject to intense criticism.

The Board justifies its approach by stating that in cases of oral agreement claims, the defenses and statements reflected in the evidence presented by the parties can be considered. However, critics argue that granting the Board such broad discretion contradicts the principle of legality prevalent in administrative law, as it would be difficult to clearly determine the legal boundaries of an agreement with vague scope.

While evaluating ancillary restraints, the Board determines whether they are directly relevant and then assesses whether they are reasonably necessary, taking into account the nature, duration, and scope of the restraint. For instance, in the sale of a shopping mall in Istanbul, if a non-compete clause prevents the seller from operating a shopping mall in the Marmara region for seven years, it is evident that such a non-compete clause would raise concerns about competition due to its excessively broad geographic scope and duration. On the other hand, if a non-compete clause is valid for a radius of a few kilometers around the shopping mall for a period of three years, this seems more appropriate and reasonable to address potential concerns about the depreciation of the buyer's investment. A similar approach would apply to no-poaching agreements. In the case of no-poaching agreements, these restrictions should be narrowly tailored to protect the value that employees bring to the enterprise.

In its decisions evaluating no-poaching agreements, the Board emphasizes that agreements related to no-poaching should be considered as clear and serious violations in terms of their nature and effects. The Board assesses that such agreements constitute violations in terms of their purpose and may lead to consumer harm.[1]

However, the Board has granted exemptions to agreements prohibiting the transfer of employees in narrowly defined, innovation-driven sectors where technical knowledge and skill are crucial. In another decision[2], the Board stipulated that for non-compete restrictions to be considered an ancillary restraint, they must meet the criteria of being "directly related and necessary to the concentration," "restrictive only for the parties," and "proportional." The Board accepted a two-year non-employment obligation proposed by the parties as an ancillary restraint because it was relevant only to the parties and the subject of the transfer, its duration was reasonable, and it was necessary for the return on the buyer's investment. These assessments could serve as references for determining whether no-poaching agreements outside of concentration operations can be considered as ancillary restraints.

In its decisions, the Board examines whether no-poaching agreements are limited in duration, whether the restriction is based on a reasonable commercial interest, whether it is reasonably justified, and whether this justification is clearly stated in the contract.

Prohibiting agreements among employers to fix wages and restrict employee mobility undoubtedly protects competition in labor markets, prevents the distortion of resource allocation, and is crucial in establishing a fair competitive environment in this area. Preserving and promoting competition in labor markets will provide better wages, benefits, and employment opportunities for workers. However, it is also clear that not every no-poaching agreement should be evaluated within this framework. Agreements that are transaction-related and reasonably necessary should also be considered under the ancillary restraint doctrine.

In the context of compliance with competition law, employers must refrain from sharing sensitive information with each other for the purpose of comparing employment conditions. While salary information is often the primary concern in this regard, when assessing sensitive information, consideration should be given to the "entirety of employment terms and conditions" that could influence an individual's decision to enter into or remain in an employment contract.

When a restriction request is made in a transaction in which one is involved, it is crucial to analyze which elements are being sought for protection with this restriction, whether there is a genuine need for this protection, and to analyze its scope correctly. A proper analysis of all these aspects will enable the parties to reach an agreement within a reasonable scope that does not violate competition laws.

Special thanks to Asya Naz Kızılırmak for his contributions.

[1] The Decision of the Competition Board dated 11.11.2021 and numbered 21-55/765-381

[2] The Decision of the Competition Board dated 18.06.2009 and numbered 09-29/602-143

 Download PDF

...
Framed Content Aggregator - Publisher | Sponsor
...
ICLG

ICLG.com is a leading global platform for legal reference, analysis and news, hosting comprehensive comparative legal guides and research tools that cover law in more than 191 jurisdictions across 59 practice areas. ICLG.com also provides daily legal news and legal conference directories, as well as online purchasing of the renowned International Comparative Legal Guide series of print publications. https://iclg.com

SKU code : AF830329-6442-8D38-44C1-2795C5537658
Delivery Format:
HTML ...

Immediate Delivery
...Access Rights | Content Availability:
...

...

The content of this subscriber knowledge library area, the technology platform and tools are provided for information purposes only. No legal liability or other responsibility is accepted for any errors, omissions, or any loss, damage or inconvenience caused as a result of reliance on such information, or statements on this site, or any site to which these pages connect, since we cannot control the content or take responsibility for pages maintained by external providers. Where we provide links to sites, we do not by doing so endorse any information or opinions appearing in them. This courseware includes resources copyrighted and open educational resources (OER) by multiple individuals and organizations. If someone else is given access to your account login information, that person has read, understands and accepts the Conditions of Use for this platform.

...

Objectives and Study Scope

This study has assimilated knowledge and insight from business and subject-matter experts, and from a broad spectrum of market initiatives. Building on this research, the objectives of this market research report is to provide actionable intelligence on opportunities alongside the market size of various segments, as well as fact-based information on key factors influencing the market- growth drivers, industry-specific challenges and other critical issues in terms of detailed analysis and impact.

The report in its entirety provides a comprehensive overview of the current global condition, as well as notable opportunities and challenges. The analysis reflects market size, latest trends, growth drivers, threats, opportunities, as well as key market segments. The study addresses market dynamics in several geographic segments along with market analysis for the current market environment and future scenario over the forecast period. The report also segments the market into various categories based on the product, end user, application, type, and region.
The report also studies various growth drivers and restraints impacting the  market, plus a comprehensive market and vendor landscape in addition to a SWOT analysis of the key players.  This analysis also examines the competitive landscape within each market. Market factors are assessed by examining barriers to entry and market opportunities. Strategies adopted by key players including recent developments, new product launches, merger and acquisitions, and other insightful updates are provided.

Research Process & Methodology

...

We leverage extensive primary research, our contact database, knowledge of companies and industry relationships, patent and academic journal searches, and Institutes and University associate links to frame a strong visibility in the markets and technologies we cover.

We draw on available data sources and methods to profile developments. We use computerised data mining methods and analytical techniques, including cluster and regression modelling, to identify patterns from publicly available online information on enterprise web sites.
Historical, qualitative and quantitative information is obtained principally from confidential and proprietary sources, professional network, annual reports, investor relationship presentations, and expert interviews, about key factors, such as recent trends in industry performance and identify factors underlying those trends - drivers, restraints, opportunities, and challenges influencing the growth of the market, for both, the supply and demand sides.
In addition to our own desk research, various secondary sources, such as Hoovers, Dun & Bradstreet, Bloomberg BusinessWeek, Statista, are referred to identify key players in the industry, supply chain and market size, percentage shares, splits, and breakdowns into segments and subsegments with respect to individual growth trends, prospects, and contribution to the total market.

Research Portfolio Sources:

  • BBC Monitoring

  • BMI Research: Company Reports, Industry Reports, Special Reports, Industry Forecast Scenario

  • CIMB: Company Reports, Daily Market News, Economic Reports, Industry Reports, Strategy Reports, and Yearbooks

  • Dun & Bradstreet: Country Reports, Country Riskline Reports, Economic Indicators 5yr Forecast, and Industry Reports

  • EMIS: EMIS Insight and EMIS Dealwatch

  • Enerdata: Energy Data Set, Energy Market Report, Energy Prices, LNG Trade Data and World Refineries Data

  • Euromoney: China Law and Practice, Emerging Markets, International Tax Review, Latin Finance, Managing Intellectual Property, Petroleum Economist, Project Finance, and Euromoney Magazine

  • Euromonitor International: Industry Capsules, Local Company Profiles, Sector Capsules

  • Fitch Ratings: Criteria Reports, Outlook Report, Presale Report, Press Releases, Special Reports, Transition Default Study Report

  • FocusEconomics: Consensus Forecast Country Reports

  • Ken Research: Industry Reports, Regional Industry Reports and Global Industry Reports

  • MarketLine: Company Profiles and Industry Profiles

  • OECD: Economic Outlook, Economic Surveys, Energy Prices and Taxes, Main Economic Indicators, Main Science and Technology Indicators, National Accounts, Quarterly International Trade Statistics

  • Oxford Economics: Global Industry Forecasts, Country Economic Forecasts, Industry Forecast Data, and Monthly Industry Briefings

  • Progressive Digital Media: Industry Snapshots, News, Company Profiles, Energy Business Review

  • Project Syndicate: News Commentary

  • Technavio: Global Market Assessment Reports, Regional Market Assessment Reports, and Market Assessment Country Reports

  • The Economist Intelligence Unit: Country Summaries, Industry Briefings, Industry Reports and Industry Statistics

Global Business Reviews, Research Papers, Commentary & Strategy Reports

  • World Bank

  • World Trade Organization

  • The Financial Times

  • The Wall Street Journal

  • The Wall Street Transcript

  • Bloomberg

  • Standard & Poor’s Industry Surveys

  • Thomson Research

  • Thomson Street Events

  • Reuter 3000 Xtra

  • OneSource Business

  • Hoover’s

  • MGI

  • LSE

  • MIT

  • ERA

  • BBVA

  • IDC

  • IdExec

  • Moody’s

  • Factiva

  • Forrester Research

  • Computer Economics

  • Voice and Data

  • SIA / SSIR

  • Kiplinger Forecasts

  • Dialog PRO

  • LexisNexis

  • ISI Emerging Markets

  • McKinsey

  • Deloitte

  • Oliver Wyman

  • Faulkner Information Services

  • Accenture

  • Ipsos

  • Mintel

  • Statista

  • Bureau van Dijk’s Amadeus

  • EY

  • PwC

  • Berg Insight

  • ABI research

  • Pyramid Research

  • Gartner Group

  • Juniper Research

  • MarketsandMarkets

  • GSA

  • Frost and Sullivan Analysis

  • McKinsey Global Institute

  • European Mobile and Mobility Alliance

  • Open Europe

M&A and Risk Management | Regulation

  • Thomson Mergers & Acquisitions

  • MergerStat

  • Profound

  • DDAR

  • ISS Corporate Governance

  • BoardEx

  • Board Analyst

  • Securities Mosaic

  • Varonis

  • International Tax and Business Guides

  • CoreCompensation

  • CCH Research Network

...
Forecast methodology

The future outlook “forecast” is based on a set of statistical methods such as regression analysis, industry specific drivers as well as analyst evaluations, as well as analysis of the trends that influence economic outcomes and business decision making.
The Global Economic Model is covering the political environment, the macroeconomic environment, market opportunities, policy towards free enterprise and competition, policy towards foreign investment, foreign trade and exchange controls, taxes, financing, the labour market and infrastructure. We aim update our market forecast to include the latest market developments and trends.

Forecasts, Data modelling and indicator normalisation

Review of independent forecasts for the main macroeconomic variables by the following organizations provide a holistic overview of the range of alternative opinions:

  • Cambridge Econometrics (CE)

  • The Centre for Economic and Business Research (CEBR)

  • Experian Economics (EE)

  • Oxford Economics (OE)

As a result, the reported forecasts derive from different forecasters and may not represent the view of any one forecaster over the whole of the forecast period. These projections provide an indication of what is, in our view most likely to happen, not what it will definitely happen.

Short- and medium-term forecasts are based on a “demand-side” forecasting framework, under the assumption that supply adjusts to meet demand either directly through changes in output or through the depletion of inventories.
Long-term projections rely on a supply-side framework, in which output is determined by the availability of labour and capital equipment and the growth in productivity.
Long-term growth prospects, are impacted by factors including the workforce capabilities, the openness of the economy to trade, the legal framework, fiscal policy, the degree of government regulation.

Direct contribution to GDP
The method for calculating the direct contribution of an industry to GDP, is to measure its ‘gross value added’ (GVA); that is, to calculate the difference between the industry’s total pre­tax revenue and its total bought­in costs (costs excluding wages and salaries).

Forecasts of GDP growth: GDP = CN+IN+GS+NEX

GDP growth estimates take into account:

  • Consumption, expressed as a function of income, wealth, prices and interest rates;

  • Investment as a function of the return on capital and changes in capacity utilization; Government spending as a function of intervention initiatives and state of the economy;

  • Net exports as a function of global economic conditions.

CLICK BELOW TO LEARN MORE
...

Market Quantification
All relevant markets are quantified utilizing revenue figures for the forecast period. The Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) within each segment is used to measure growth and to extrapolate data when figures are not publicly available.

Revenues

Our market segments reflect major categories and subcategories of the global market, followed by an analysis of statistical data covering national spending and international trade relations and patterns. Market values reflect revenues paid by the final customer / end user to vendors and service providers either directly or through distribution channels, excluding VAT. Local currencies are converted to USD using the yearly average exchange rates of local currencies to the USD for the respective year as provided by the IMF World Economic Outlook Database.

Industry Life Cycle Market Phase

Market phase is determined using factors in the Industry Life Cycle model. The adapted market phase definitions are as follows:

  • Nascent: New market need not yet determined; growth begins increasing toward end of cycle

  • Growth: Growth trajectory picks up; high growth rates

  • Mature: Typically fewer firms than growth phase, as dominant solutions continue to capture the majority of market share and market consolidation occurs, displaying lower growth rates that are typically on par with the general economy

  • Decline: Further market consolidation, rapidly declining growth rates

...

The Global Economic Model
The Global Economic Model brings together macroeconomic and sectoral forecasts for quantifying the key relationships.

The model is a hybrid statistical model that uses macroeconomic variables and inter-industry linkages to forecast sectoral output. The model is used to forecast not just output, but prices, wages, employment and investment. The principal variables driving the industry model are the components of final demand, which directly or indirectly determine the demand facing each industry. However, other macroeconomic assumptions — in particular exchange rates, as well as world commodity prices — also enter into the equation, as well as other industry specific factors that have been or are expected to impact.

  • Vector Auto Regression (VAR) statistical models capturing the linear interdependencies among multiple time series, are best used for short-term forecasting, whereby shocks to demand will generate economic cycles that can be influenced by fiscal and monetary policy.

  • Dynamic-Stochastic Equilibrium (DSE) models replicate the behaviour of the economy by analyzing the interaction of economic variables, whereby output is determined by supply side factors, such as investment, demographics, labour participation and productivity.

  • Dynamic Econometric Error Correction (DEEC) modelling combines VAR and DSE models by estimating the speed at which a dependent variable returns to its equilibrium after a shock, as well as assessing the impact of a company, industry, new technology, regulation, or market change. DEEC modelling is best suited for forecasting.

Forecasts of GDP growth per capita based on these factors can then be combined with demographic projections to give forecasts for overall GDP growth.
Wherever possible, publicly available data from official sources are used for the latest available year. Qualitative indicators are normalised (on the basis of: Normalised x = (x - Min(x)) / (Max(x) - Min(x)) where Min(x) and Max(x) are, the lowest and highest values for any given indicator respectively) and then aggregated across categories to enable an overall comparison. The normalised value is then transformed into a positive number on a scale of 0 to 100. The weighting assigned to each indicator can be changed to reflect different assumptions about their relative importance.

CLICK BELOW TO LEARN MORE
...

The principal explanatory variable in each industry’s output equation is the Total Demand variable, encompassing exogenous macroeconomic assumptions, consumer spending and investment, and intermediate demand for goods and services by sectors of the economy for use as inputs in the production of their own goods and services.

Elasticities
Elasticity measures the response of one economic variable to a change in another economic variable, whether the good or service is demanded as an input into a final product or whether it is the final product, and provides insight into the proportional impact of different economic actions and policy decisions.
Demand elasticities measure the change in the quantity demanded of a particular good or service as a result of changes to other economic variables, such as its own price, the price of competing or complementary goods and services, income levels, taxes.
Demand elasticities can be influenced by several factors. Each of these factors, along with the specific characteristics of the product, will interact to determine its overall responsiveness of demand to changes in prices and incomes.
The individual characteristics of a good or service will have an impact, but there are also a number of general factors that will typically affect the sensitivity of demand, such as the availability of substitutes, whereby the elasticity is typically higher the greater the number of available substitutes, as consumers can easily switch between different products.
The degree of necessity. Luxury products and habit forming ones, typically have a higher elasticity.
Proportion of the budget consumed by the item. Products that consume a large portion of the consumer’s budget tend to have greater elasticity.
Elasticities tend to be greater over the long run because consumers have more time to adjust their behaviour.
Finally, if the product or service is an input into a final product then the price elasticity will depend on the price elasticity of the final product, its cost share in the production costs, and the availability of substitutes for that good or service.

Prices
Prices are also forecast using an input-output framework. Input costs have two components; labour costs are driven by wages, while intermediate costs are computed as an input-output weighted aggregate of input sectors’ prices. Employment is a function of output and real sectoral wages, that are forecast as a function of whole economy growth in wages. Investment is forecast as a function of output and aggregate level business investment.

CLICK BELOW TO LEARN MORE
...